Back in April, I had the opportunity to present a paper on the economics of urban planning at the New Zealand Planning Institute’s annual conference. The paper, which benefited from the support of my employer, MRCagney, and discussions with a menagerie of planners and other economists, is now available online for anyone who’s interested. (As is inevitable, some of the table headings didn’t come out quite right in the online version. Oh well.)

The aim of the paper was to illuminate some of the trade-offs – and unintended consequences – that can occur as a result of urban planning. It presents three short case studies that illustrate different aspects of the choices facing us in urban planning:

  • Minimum parking requirements, which were aimed at managing congestion and keeping down parking search costs – but which actually managed to increase congestion, reduce the viability of public transport, walking, and cycling, and require us to use scarce land inefficiently
  • Heritage preservation policies, which are attempting to balance the preservation of “aesthetic externalities” from nice old buildings with the process of urban change
  • Opportunities for new development – is it possible to build affordable housing in areas where land prices are high? Can we just keep building standalone houses, or are higher density housing choices required?

As it’s a conference paper rather than a research paper, it focuses on pulling together some disparate perspectives on urban planning rather than evaluating policies and recommending specific approaches. If you’re interested in a brief, non-technical overview of the subject, give it a read. Here’s an excerpt:

I’d like to close by discussing one major trade-off we face: the choice between low-density cities and affordable cities. It is simply mathematically impossible to combine high land prices, low densities, and home affordability. In areas with high land prices – which we would expect to see in any economically successful city – we need to ask: would we prefer to have affordable housing or low densities?

urban policy trilemma

We can think of real-world examples of places that conform to each edge of the triangle. It’s easy to find low-density, affordable housing in (say) Pokeno or Huntly, as land values are low enough to sustain it. But in inner-city Auckland, high land prices mean that we must choose between our desire for space and our need for affordable housing. We’ve resolved these trade-offs differently in different areas. In Ponsonby, we’ve preferred to maintain lower-density heritage housing, which has priced many people out of the suburb entirely. By contrast, building many apartments at all price points has allowed the city centre itself to remain affordable.

Some people argue that Auckland should aim to bring land costs down in order to improve housing affordability. In my view, this view ignores the market realities. High land prices are an indicator of urban success – they demonstrate that people and businesses want to be there. We may be able to lower them through, say, a deep and prolonged recession or years of net emigration. But it’s unlikely that the benefits of reduced land prices would justify the economic and social costs of doing so.

Furthermore, greenfield land supply alone won’t solve our problems. While land does tend to be cheaper on the edge of the city, households that locate there tend to incur higher transport costs. Previous empirical work has shown that higher commuting costs entirely offset savings on housing cost in fringe suburbs (Mattingly and Morrissey, 2013; Nunns et al, 2014). As a result, if we want affordable housing we have no choice but to deliver it in places that are accessible to employment, education, and amenities.

Fortunately, we have choices. Technological innovations – steel-framed buildings, indoor plumbing, and elevators – have freed us from the tyranny of horizontally. We have the option to build up, if we are willing to take it.

Finally, while writing this paper, I put a fair bit of thought into how economists, urban planners, and citizens in general talk about urban policy issues. In my view, many of the disagreements that we have when talking about urban policies are best thought of as differences in terminology, not differences in values. At the end of the day, most people would like to live in a city that gives them good choices about how to live, work, and play, and doesn’t waste too much of their time or money. But sometimes we talk about that in different terms.

One morning, I was lucky enough to run across a scene that illustrates how good urban policies can enable outcomes that different people may find pleasing in different ways. I took this picture on the Fort Street shared space, where a loading dock has been converted into a container cafe. They’ve slapped up a mural on the wall, put out a few chairs, and gone into business:

20150210_100533 copy

Now, as a dour, fun-averse economist I find this scene beautiful because it shows underutilised resources being put to higher and better uses. Multifactor productivity in action! An urban designer or architect may find it beautiful for the way it’s “activated” a blank loading bay as a people space. A passer-by may simply enjoy the way it looks, or be enticed to go in to try their coffee. Others may appreciate the employment opportunities it makes available.

All of which demonstrates one of the wonderful traits of cities: how their diversity and vitality can satisfy the needs and desires of many different people.

Share this

31 comments

  1. You make good points, but present the wrong binary choice: density vs. greenfield. The city needs both high density in high value areas and affordable low density in low value areas. Currently we have restrictions causing high cost medium density in high value areas and high cost ultra low density in low value areas – our prices are uniformly high. Correcting one by railing against the other will not improve the situation. What we should consider is price vs. value.

    Some people argue that Auckland should aim to bring land costs down in order to improve housing affordability. In my view, this view ignores the market realities. High land prices are an indicator of urban success – they demonstrate that people and businesses want to be there. We may be able to lower them through, say, a deep and prolonged recession or years of net emigration. But it’s unlikely that the benefits of reduced land prices would justify the economic and social costs of doing so.

    High land prices are always not indicative of a successful city, but can be induced by us restricting brownfield development and eliminating greenfield. One potential cause of a region experiencing a prolonged recession and net emigration is having high structural costs (land value is a structural cost) compared to alternative locations. Greenfield industrial land supply needs to be made available at low cost, otherwise new businesses will locate to alternative regions with lower structural cost. The only place available for new industrial land is the city fringe and these will need workers, but our only accommodation available at the city fringe is currently extremely low density/high price (lifestyle block) semi-urban. The city needs to have greenfield low-medium density housing near these sites to prevent these workers having to commute outwards (another high cost).

    1. I think there’s a difference between making more low-priced land available, which is what you’re talking about, and *reducing* land values throughout the city, which is what I was taking aim at.

      The former idea makes sense, at long as infrastructure is priced efficiently. The latter does not, at least if you want a successful economy.

      By the way, do you have any examples of cities that have gone into economic decline due to high land prices? My (admitted not comprehensive) reading of the literature suggests that overly restrictive planning has constrained the *growth* of successful places like San Francisco, but I haven’t found any evidence that it has flipped cities from success to failure. The cities that have failed seem to have done so more as a result of their over-dependence on declining industries – see e.g. http://www.nber.org/papers/w13710.

      1. Liverpool is a prime example of how artificially high land rent can destroy a city’s competitiveness and cause people to look elsewhere. I find it hard to believe its population decline over the past few decades would have been anywhere near as significant if it were not burdened by excessive growth regulations. Contrast it to Detroit, which is starting to experience somewhat of a renaissance largely due to the low cost of living enticing young entrepreneurial folks.

        1. Got any references to studies on the topic?

          My understanding has always been that Liverpool declined economically starting in the 1960s and 1970s for two reasons:
          1. The advent of containerised shipping, which massively reduced labour requirements on the docks
          2. The decline of English manufacturing as a result of reduced trade barriers and the entry of more productive competitors in east Asia.

          And, of course, Yoko Ono breaking up the Beatles 😉

        2. Plus population decline, or rather redistribution, through a strategic regional decentralisation: New Towns, several motorways and an evolving functional conglomeration with Manchester.
          Sad thing is, some of those new towns offering Le Corb style motopia really aren’t very appetising any more (Warrington, anyone?) whereas Liverpool and Manchester are resurgent. Urban bones enable reinvention and a new future, ring roads and cul-de-sacs less so.

        3. I’m getting a little frustrated by the number of times Liverpool is referred to as an example of a declining city. Yes as Peter Nunns stated there was decline in the 60s/70’s ( as local population were forced to move into new towns with no work opportunities). But look at Liverpool now – the city centre is thriving, massive investment in retail, leisure and residential property. Liverpool, sound as a pound, still fab.

      2. There are examples of cities where the price of property collapsed and then settled at a much lower level.

    2. Peter you are avoiding the issue that high land prices may reflect structural problems in the property market.

      For instance land value taxes because it discourages land banking and encourages intensification lowers property prices. The ratio of value or amenity to price improves

      There may be other reforms of transport and planning that may improve the ratio of amenity to price in the property market?

      Also there is a dynamic time process with the density supply response where not only are prices high they are inflating at a rate faster than the productive economy can cope with.

  2. Yeah right; not very well thought through at all.
    “The city needs to have greenfield low-medium density housing near these sites to prevent these workers having to commute outwards”
    Ok so, one person in the household works close to where they work (if only) and the other works the other side of town. This is not just common but more the norm.
    Oh and that container cafe on Fort Street has not only gone into business but gone into a pretty popular business.

    1. Except that by the law on averages your commute across town is shorter if you are 5 k from the centre than if you are 50.

  3. “would we prefer to have affordable housing or low densities?”

    Low density and affordable housing are essentially the same thing, at least in comparison to your average apartment, which usually has a per square metre price at least ten times that of a house on a section. That’s why houses in most NZ towns and cities (which are mostly low density) are vastly cheaper than a small apartment in Auckland. If the concept of high density was an enabler of affordable housing (often claimed, but untrue), we would see apartments for sale for under $50k, which is what they would be if the per square metre price of an average kiwi house applied.

    1. Yawn, boring troll is boring. I don’t care how many square metres my house has, I want a bedroom bathroom and kitchen, and if that costs $300,000 as an apartment, or $600,000 here in Birkenhead then I don’t care.

    2. I think you’ve got a fair point about the per-m2 costs. The construction costs to build a one-storey building than it is to build a six-storey building.

      However, in an area where land costs are high, that apartment can be a lot cheaper than an equivalently-sized house. That’s because you’re splitting the costs for the expensive land over a much larger number of dwellings.

      Finally, you need to realise that housing affordability has both a numerator and a denominator. I could probably reduce my housing costs by moving to a small town. But the loss of income from having to take a lower-paying job would more than offset the savings.

    3. A roof over your head is a roof over your head no matter how many m2 it covers. I consider anything above ~80 m2 pure luxury with no real effect on quality of life. You just get used to the extra space and fill it with crap stuff. If you have extra money to burn, sure, why not, there are cool things you can do with your own house. As long as it’s not in a galaxy far, far away …

      Heh, a search on a certain site for property in Auckland City under $500k:
          442 results for apartments
          72 results for houses

    4. “apartments for sale for under $50k, which is what they would be if the per square metre price of an average kiwi house applied”

      You need to check your sums, mate. I’m looking at construction cost data right now, and the cost to build average-sized standalone homes is more like $1700-2000/m2. You’d get a 25-30m2 apartment for that.

      “average apartment, which usually has a per square metre price at least ten times that of a house on a section”

      Yeah, nah. It doesn’t cost $20,000 per square metre to construct an apartment.

      1. When you say construction for standalone homes is more like $1700-2000/m2 that is for bottom end specification. It is construction of house only, landscaping, infrastructure drives, roads etc. are additional. Apartments construction rates currently start from $3000/sqm for bigger projects, low spec. Smaller (or higher spec.) apartment buildings will start at $4000sqm.

        Of course a nice house or apartment is going to be 3, 4 or 5K/sqm and the really nice houses can be $10k per sqm without too much effort.

        A 50K say 50sqm apartment would be a retail price of $1000/sqm which would indicate a construction price of $330 per square metre. I’d like to know where they are constructing an ‘average kiwi house’ for that money?

        1. Thanks for the info! I’ve found it interesting how variable estimates of the cost to construct high-rise buildings can be. Some of the QS figures I’ve used in this paper are probably at the low end of the range – doesn’t really change the direction of the analysis, but it does move some of the figures around.

        2. Apartment construction prices are escalating at the moment so $3000/sqm today was probably $2400 1 year or 18 months ago, so your QS estimates might just be a bit older?.

        3. You’re right, they’re about a year or year and a half old at this point. Yikes. That’s some serious construction cost inflation.

          A question, since you obviously know your stuff. If I were looking for an appropriate price series (e.g. a producer price index or capital goods price index) to account for apartment construction costs, what would you recommend?

        4. not sure sorry. They seem to be very variable depending on capacity. There’s very few builders in Auckland capable of bigger multi-floor residential (and some that think they are that aren’t) so once they and their subbies are booked prices escalate very quick, conversely in a year or two if they have no new projects on the horizon prices will drop pretty quick too.

    5. No, low density cannot equal affordable when the land is high value. Herne Bay is close to a lot of high paying jobs on good northward facing hillside with marvelous views and has quite a lot of low density housing.

      Of course an apartment will never be as low cost to build as a simple house, but it minimises the shared land cost of the structure.

  4. If the trilemma only works on the condition of us having a successful city, in an unsuccessful city the triangle would be distorted.

    Lifestyle blocks are ultra low density, completely unaffordable and have low land price compared to the rest of the city – completely outside the logic of the triangle. Auckland is surrounded by lifestyle blocks and this suggests Auckland is not a successful city.

    1. Nope they are just the extreme point of low density in the triangle. Houses need only fall in the lines not necessarily between two points

        1. The lifestyle blocks don’t cause cheap land, the land is cheap because it is far away from things. It could also be cheap if a lifestyle block zoning stops it from being used for a higher value use.

          It would probably be clearer if the top of the triangle was ‘proximity’ rather than ‘high land prices’.

        2. I don’t think lifestyle block land is cheap because the land is far away from things, I think the lifestyle block land is cheap because it is stopped from being suburban (high density). Suburban is 20x denser than lifestyle block and of much higher value.

          Half disagree, half agree.

        3. Yes agreed. Thats what I meant when I said “It could also be cheap if a lifestyle block zoning stops it from being used for a higher value use.”

        4. What gives with lifestyle blocks anyway? This council seems to be obsessed with density being the best thing ever and sprawl being bad, so they’ve gone created their proposed urban rural boundary. But then you look at the boundary, go visit the edge and see masses of lifestyle blocks sprawling for miles into the distance beyond. Its not rural, it’s vast areas of ultra low density housing that the council ignores. If we reclassified all of this land as urban Auckland would become denser and we would create better communities.

        5. “If we reclassified all of this land as urban Auckland would become denser and we would create better communities.”

          Much of the existing lifestyle block land is inside the rural urban boundary under the Unitary Plan. Other lifestyle areas are either unsuited to urbanisation (due to topography and stability issues) or are prohibitively expensive to service with infrastructure.

  5. Good stuff Peter!

    I hope Council reads it.

    Especially- “As a result, planning processes must have some mechanism for getting representative input from communities”

    Cause man, do they have zero interest in that…

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *