Those promoting a transport and urban outcome based around smart growth, a compact city, a more balanced transport policy and more investment in public transport, walking and cycling – instead of on road capacity – have long based their arguments on the need for change. This had some logic to it as the general trend the world was heading seemed to be towards more urban sprawl and more car dependency – which has some serious negative consequences for the economy, society and the environment. The paradigm could be summarised as follows:

The market is delivering more sprawl and more  car dependency, which is collectively a bad thing, so we must intervene in the market for the common good

Pretty much everything is couched on this world-view: from both sides of the argument actually.  On the side of smart growth and a balanced transport policy we still hear much about the need to “change behaviour”, the need to “curb urban sprawl”, the need to “get people out of their cars” and so on. On the ‘other side’ of the argument, we hear a lot of criticism about planners engaging in “social engineering”, about public transport advocates wanting to “force people” out of their cars. Essentially both sides of the debate are making the same assumption: that the market (being the aggregated wants and needs of the population) wants to deliver car-based urban sprawl. They only differ in whether this outcome should be allowed or discouraged.

One of the key things that various posts on this site over the past month or two have tried to emphasise is that this paradigm has changed. Increasingly, the evidence is pointing towards the market making a pretty radical departure from its general trends of most of the last century, with a new and thoroughly different paradigm emerging – the market actually wants less sprawl and less car dependency. People actually want to catch public transport because it makes sense for them. People want to live in central parts of the city, not on the urban periphery. People are smart enough to realise that what Auckland needs is not a whole pile more roads, but a world-class public transport system to complement our existing roading network. In short, those promoting this new paradigm no longer need to couch their arguments in terms of the need for change or the need for intervention, increasingly they can simply focus on allowing and enabling this shift to happen.

There are two key pieces of evidence in relation to this paradigm shift: traffic volumes compared to public transport patronage growth being the first and the location of housing demand (highlighted most clearly through house prices) being the other. Let’s start with traffic volumes compared to PT patronage.

Stu’s two posts a few weeks back really highlighted that the current ‘flat-lining’ of traffic growth is not only a pretty dramatic shift from constant increases over much of the last century, but also that this flat-lining has been going on now for quite a long time: seven whole years. Furthermore, a ‘de-coupling’ of traffic growth and economic growth has been going on for around 14 years now, meaning that for the first time we’re able to grow the economy without a similar level of growth in traffic volumes. And in more recent years we’ve been growing the population quite significantly but once again without a commensurate increase in traffic volumes:

The idea that traffic volumes won’t continue to increase, or at least that they might increase at a slower rate than population growth (as each person travels less) is a complete anathema to the “old paradigm”. Under that old paradigm volumes always increase by around 3-4% a year and always would. With most roading projects justified by forecasts of increasing traffic in the future (and the horrors if a road is not widened or added to cope with that increase), the huge dip in per capita travel over the past five years is utterly devastating to the business case for pretty much every new roading project. If our system for assessing such projects actually recognised this fundamental shift, which it doesn’t.

In contrast, public transport patronage in Auckland most particularly has grown in leaps and bounds over this same period – up by around a third since 2006:  Comparing the trends of traffic growth and PT patronage growth, the way to structure arguments for a shift in funding becomes clear: it’s not about what modes we should spend the money on for broader reasons (although those arguments are still valid), but a much simpler “people are using PT a lot more, people are driving less, we need to reflect that in our funding balance”. By the way, the current government funding plan spends about $27 on state highways for every dollar spent on PT infrastructure – about as ignorant of these trends as practically possible.

The second paradigm shift relates to that vexed issue of “how should Auckland grow?” The common assumption is that “the market” wants to grow through urban expansion or sprawl, and that planning intervention is required to encourage/force people to live more intensively and ‘save’ the rural hinterland. Yet again, both sides of the debate accept the paradigm that everyone wants to live on the urban edge, in a “quarter acre paradise”. However, a series of posts – this time mainly by Patrick – have highlighted that the reality these days is actually quite different.

Patrick has noted a series of articles in the NZ Herald and other overseas publications over the past few months which consistently say the same thing: house prices in the inner suburbs are soaring while (especially in the USA) they are still falling on the urban periphery. There are a wide variety of reasons given for this phenomenon, things like higher fuel prices, changing demographics, smaller household sizes, cultural shifts and so forth – all of which are interestingly similar to many of the causes that might be behind the stagnation in traffic volumes over the past seven years.

So the paradigm of “allowing sprawl or forcing/encouraging intensification” really may not be valid anymore, just like the “providing for vehicle growth or encouraging/forcing people onto public transport” is now outdated. People are changing their habits already. The trick now is to ensure that policy decisions, especially when it comes to decisions over where transport money is spent, reflect this new reality. We plan for the future, both in land-use decisions (whether to expand urban boundaries or make intensification easier) and in transport decisions (whether to spend money on holiday highways or city rail links) – let’s ensure that our decisions reflect the new reality of what people actually are doing and what people want. Not an outdated, old paradigm, version of that.

We don’t have to force change anymore, let’s allow it to happen.

Share this

20 comments

  1. “In short, those promoting this new paradigm no longer need to couch their arguments in terms of the need for change or the need for intervention, increasingly they can simply focus on allowing and enabling this shift to happen.”

    Well if the council drops the MUL/ RUB as a concept, then this would take the wind out of critics sail at a stroke. Is this what you are proposing?

    1. A good question Swan. In time, and with pricing mechanisms in place to ensure that sprawl pays its way and is not subsidised, the urban limit would probably be unnecessary.

      However in the meanwhile it seems that developers are still living in the old paradigm and to ensure we don’t subsidise the construction of vastly expensive urban areas that may not even be used much in the future, an urban limit is a necessary tool for now.

      1. Nicely put. In the absence of full capture of sprawl’s externalities, regulation of the sprawl is the only solution. Otherwise the invisible subsidisation of sprawl will ensure that Auckland spreads to create a single urban area stretching from Hamilton Airport to North Whangarei.

  2. Good summary Peter: Weirdly it is the Highway/Sprawl view [that includes the gov.] that is ‘forcing’ a one-size-fits-all model onto everyone; limiting choice.

    Forced to drive, forced to live on the periphery, especially for those with less money.

    Wow 27 to 1. That is a huge subsidy for road freight. Gov. determined to prevent any balance between road and rail developing in that sector too. I guess this welfare will have to continue as the cost of fuel keeps rising.

  3. I would really like to see that first graph with a line for Light Vehicles rather than All & Heavy. I presume this is a limitation of the original data, but it does look conspiratorially like its hiding a more dramatic downwards growth curve of light vehicle usage.
    Perhaps a OIA request should be made of NZTA for the raw data, anyone?

    1. Yes and light vehicles are by far the majority. Just shows who NZTA are really serving; welfare for road freight. Also remember buses are classed as heavy, so how much of the uptick in heavy vehicles on the Harbour Bridge, for instance, is because of the rise in PT because of the busway?

    1. Comments made in ignorance don’t reflect much about what’s happening with attitudes. The comments mentioned in that article show a pretty fundamental lack of understanding of what the CRL will do for public transport across the region. “Reasons for opposing the rail link to the airport were because of its expense, and because the benefits had not been demonstrated to ratepayers”, and those are perfectly fair criticisms. This forum has been very blunt about how poorly AT/AC have been doing at selling the CRL, and given the high numbers of tribal National voters out there who will accept every word that comes from the current government’s mouth as gospel it’s essential that AT/AC up their game dramatically.

    1. Anthony, Stonefields is not a place that even I would advocate for intensification. It is badly planned and on no transit route. Pretty much the wrong place for apartments and guess what? That’s what the market thinks too.

      Contrast with this site, close to Aotea Station but even closer to K’rd, ideal: http://www.nzherald.co.nz/building-construction/news/article.cfm?c_id=24&objectid=10798162 :Worth a read.

      Cam your link is evidence of Cameron Brewer’s Mayoral campaign winding up, this is a fire he is hurling petrol on, while running the Nikki Kaye defence: ‘I support the CRL but but there’s no way pay for it?’. But also a failure by Len and the Council to communicate about the CRL well enough.

  4. Yep think that’s correct Patrick. If you read the article you’ll notice 48% off respondants are in favour of the airport line which suggests most people don’t understand the importance of the CRL.

  5. Need to get Australian developers involved if few NZ developers have the confidence to build high-quality apartments. There was an article in the Sun Herald in Sydney recently (unfortunately no internet version) on how apartment developers were building to a market wanting units close to public transport.

    Australian developers could be attracted to New Zealand because of lower wages for building workers.

    1. There is a huge amount of apartment choice in Australia. Check out http://www.realestate.com.au/buy for any of the large cities and select apartments and units. It’s apartment heaven, and in general I think the build quality is better and the apartments feel more modern.

      1. That’s because Australia believes in regulating markets, not leaving them to their own devices. Pretty much every failure around building quality (form, materials, methods) in NZ is directly related to National’s firm adherence to “The market solves all, so we’ll leave the industries to look after themselves” principles. They gutted construction controls in the 90s, along with their mates who controlled TLAs and set design standards, and we now have what we have: shitty stock that gives intensity haters something to wave around as a demonstration of what to expect if we try again, and that puts off buyers/renters who might otherwise be interested in that space.

        It’s also heavily responsible for the shortage of housing stock generally, because an entire style and near-on a full decade of housing stock are considered deeply suspect. The Herald had an article last week about a woman in Meadowbank (a suburb that has rising prices) who cannot get offers on her house because it’s got monolithic plaster cladding and nobody wants to touch it despite it not being a leaky home.

  6. Sprawl from Whangarei to Tauranga serviced by 3 pipes.
    1. Freight: Northland – Auckland – Wiri – Te Rapa – Ruakura – Tauranga
    2. Sprint passenger (90 – 110km\h): Whangarei – Albany – Auckland CBD – Manukau – Hamilton – Tauranga
    3. Passenger service (60-80km\h): ever Town.

    1. 1: There’s a single-track line to Tauranga and to Northland. The rectification thereof will cost more than the CRL. Not going to happen with this government. They’re not even interested in bringing the Northland line up to ordinary operating standard, never mind double-tracking it and upgrading it to be a high-volume freight corridor.

      2: So slow? The EMUs on order for our commuter rail can do 110km/h, and our narrow-gauge rail can handle up to about 160km/h if constructed properly. If we were going to do real inter-city train services, we should be looking to be dramatically faster than road traffic.

      3: As above. Our electric trains will be able to do much quicker than you suggest. Even a “metro rail” service of the kind that Nick (I think. Or is it Matt L?) keeps mooting for the Harbour crossing and servicing the Shore can do 80+km/h. Hell, the buses on the NBW could legally do 90km/h if the NBW didn’t have a lower limit.

  7. The three pipes exist, rail and two motor vehicle lanes. So do some smaller pipes Gas, phone, electricity, Water Waikato river to Wellsford, oil Whangarei to Wiri, (I remember see something about extending this south a few years back ??) What I am thinking about is can we improve the LOS along these 3 transport pipes with out adding more pipes (transport lanes).
    1. Freight: between Tauranga – Southdown looks to have spare capacity. Southdown to Auckland port looks restricted to off peck hours, Auckland to Whangarei is in need of $150m?? of investment to be competitive.
    2. Sprint: Whangarei to Manukau and Tauranga – Manukau both 2 1/2 hours average speed 80 km/h off peak by car. (I have a friend who lived in Masterton commuted to and from Wellington airport area each way each day 2 1/2 hours by rail and bus) not the commuted I would do, but there are people willing to do this.
    The Question is where do we add pipes to improve LOS and not spend endlessly.
    3. Stop service: This is for normal people and this exists with intercity buses and regional Council services,

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *