There have been a series of articles in the NZ Herald over the past week talking about dire shortages in rental properties in Auckland, particularly in the inner suburbs. This article in particular highlighted the shortage in available properties there are in places where people so obviously want to live:

The shortage was acute in the inner-city suburbs, she said.

“I don’t think there’s enough rental properties near the city … Most people will have to take their rose-tinted glasses off and say they have to live further out in the suburbs.

“Give me a million houses in Ponsonby. People love Ponsonby.”

Rental property owner Sue Beesley put up a listing for a central apartment overnight on Monday. By the time she checked online yesterday, more than 600 people had taken an interest.

“It’s a very busy time… A lot of people are trying to shift,” she said.

In some cases, prospective tenants are going to pretty extreme measures to get a place, as explained further in this article:

Desperate house hunters are sending realtors full CVs with photographs before viewings – which they turn up to with applications already filled out – and one renter says he has been up against offers to pay $100 extra a week.

You would think that with demand being so high for housing in the inner suburbs that we would be seeing more redevelopment here. But, for some reason it just isn’t happening – with building consents at a 46 year low, which is just staggering:

There were fewer building consents granted for new dwellings in 2011 than in any calendar year in 46 years, figures released by Statistics New Zealand show.

There were building consents granted for 13,662 new dwellings in the 12 months to December 31, down 12.4 per cent on the year to December 2010, and the lowest since the series began in 1965, Stats NZ said.

That included 1,156 consents for apartment units, which was up 23 per cent from 2010. Excluding apartments there were 12,506 building consents granted for dwellings through 2011, down 14.7 per cent from the year before.

Stats NZ said there was NZ$4.925 billion worth of residential building work in 2011, down 12 per cent from 2010 to its lowest level for a calendar year in 10 years.

While it’s positive to see the boost in apartments being built, clearly it isn’t enough – more housing supply is needed in the parts of Auckland where people most want to live: the inner suburbs. Another recent NZ Herald editorial attempts to join the dots together on the issue:

Normally in these circumstances the demand would bid up the price of houses too but that is not happening. Auckland house prices went so high during the last property boom that they far exceeded sensible affordability levels as a proportion of incomes…

…The only practical answer to high rents and unaffordable prices is to increase the supply of new houses.

If young adults today are to aspire to home ownership as their parents could, the building industry has to be expanded and governments must ensure that nothing stands in the way of construction of the type of houses these people want.

Their need is too important to be fodder for a political argument between land developers and city planners as to whether urban limits or land banking are aggravating the housing shortage.

The editorial seems to tentatively link this issue with the battle that’s currently going on over whether the Council’s spatial plan should allow more sprawl or not, but this seems to miss the point. The huge demand is in the inner suburbs. That’s where people want to live. That’s where we need more housing. Why isn’t it happening?

  • Has the government’s changes to taxation of property (unable to write off depreciation and making tax avoidance more difficult) discouraged investment in residential development?
  • Has the collapse of finance companies in 2007/2008 meant that developers simply can’t find the money to undertake redevelopment?
  • Are council’s planning rules in these areas of highest demand too stringent, and are they making it impossible for developments to stack up financially?

As an example of failure to grasp the appeal of centrally located properties there may also be a problem in the banking sector as recent comment from Simon showed:

 I’m a case in point. I’m 31, single, I had a good year, scraped together a deposit and went apartment shopping. I didn’t much feel like leaving the inner suburbs. I found a really nice apartment I really liked. It had good light and a big balcony and a high stud and a big park across the road. It was built post-leaky, the price was right and I thought: yes. The bank wanted a 30% deposit, plus security over my parents’ place. I gave up and bought a house on minimum deposit in the suburbs.

Okay so the banks got burnt a little from their own over-enthusiasm on apartments during the bubble, but this looks like an overreaction and like they really don’t understand this market well enough to differentiate between good and poor properties.

One issue that needs discussing is whether we are in fact undergoing a big shift in housing patterns back to renting, perhaps as big as the post war growth in home ownership and suburban spread, that was actively incentivised by successive governments. There is plenty of evidence that this is happening here and it is consistent with changes in other OECD countries. More NZ Herald articles here and here:

Aucklanders who own their own homes have declined from 74 per cent in the 1986 Census to 58.7 per cent last year, according to Statistics New Zealand’s household economic survey.

The Herald of course doesn’t pause for a moment to consider whether a strong rental market could be part of a solution and not a cause for panic, quoting this authority [bizarrely discussing another issue]:

Prime Minister John Key said in 2010, when Chinese investors first sought to buy the Crafar farms, that he would “hate to see New Zealanders as tenants in their own country”.

And of course both articles above quote ACT’s productivity commission blaming the council’s Urban Limit for the problem, but does at least print an opposing view to this for the first time.

The council yesterday noted the commission’s concern that its aim for a more compact city would worsen the problem of housing affordability.

But its submission said the commission had failed to demonstrate that releasing more sections outside the existing urban limit was the solution.

This was likely to pile on significant costs for providers of water and transport services.

The council called for further investigation into interventions in the housing market to help developers cater for low- to medium-income groups.

So it does seem as though there’s some kind of market failure going on here and a political battle about it. We should be getting more housing, but we’re not – and the explanation doesn’t seem to be that simple. But it’s certainly an issue we cannot continue to ignore. But other than criticise the city council’s proposed plan, and boosting the demand at the top end of the market through tax cuts [as Bernard Hickey pointed out recently on Twitter, below], very little is proposed at the national level.

This of course fits with the default setting of the government, still a touching faith in the market, and a refusal to consider that it has any role in assisting the less well off in its policy settings. Isn’t it the case that markets are useful tools, but terrible masters and even worse gods, as we have recently so plainly seen?

The article above does also note that the decline in home ownership mirrors the removal of state policies designed to help people at the edge of  affordability into ownership [Does everything go back to the reforms of the 1980s and 90s?].

A shift in state housing policy further widened the divide. The right to capitalise the family benefit to buy a first home ended in 1986. State lending for home ownership stopped in the 90s.

Another change in 1992 allowed investors who owned rental properties through qualifying companies to offset losses on the properties, where the rent fell short of mortgage payments, against the owners’ other income. But they could still take the profits of capital gains tax-free when they sold.

Officials estimated in 2008 that the ability to deduct losses meant an investor would be willing to pay $25,000 more for a median-priced house than someone who planned to live there.

The Smiths borrowed the full cost of buying their two rental properties five years ago. “We have benefited from generous tax schemes,” says Anita.

Says Nigel: “We win either way. Either you are getting the tax break, or you’re winning because you’re getting enough rent to cover the mortgage.”

So yes I do think there are things that the council can do. Especially involvement with state agencies and private developers on specific redevelopments [Like the Melbourne Housing Commission?] and with planning regulations, especially ways of defining certain areas on the city fringe and on transport routes for higher density development with relaxed car parking requirements and where possible increased building height. However allowing expensive new homes way out in the country-side will provide no relief for all those people that want to live affordably in the city. And nor will distant tract housing on the fringes help for the same reasons while also condemning their inhabitants into transport poverty and employment inflexibility. Trying to force people out there is likely to end in market failures as well as committing us to insane levels of extended infrastructure spending. So isn’t this really is a way bigger issue and needs some leadership at the national level, including around the distortions in the tax system, despite the government’s determination to wash their hands of it and blame the council?

Share this

29 comments

  1. Interesting article Patrick.

    I think you and I are trying to address the same problem (actually we are) but going around two very different ways in doing so?

    I am not sure whether you want a more of a Command and Control approach getting these dwellings built or allowing a more liberal approach where the council just zones for a density maximum, sets some basic urban design and environment guide lines and allow the market to try and solve the housing issue through demand and supply – with the State also coming in for some State Housing there and there as per required?

    As for me, I was inclining for the more semi-liberal approach – something mentioned in my submission and also will be running on commentary soon. 🙂

  2. What will perhaps be most interesting is if/when district plan rules are significantly changes in the inner suburbs to promote more intensification, what the take up is from developers. The articles above suggest that, if planning rules are the problem, then changing those rules should lead to a lot more units being built in those inner suburbs. Crucially this should also include radical changes to parking rules, which typically contribute more than just about anything else to limiting the possible density of development on a site.

  3. I think one possible solution to the problem is for the council to give development concessions for ‘affordable housing’. It could work something like this:
    Developer comes up with a proposal for a medium/high density development that meets the councils criteria and can get a commercial return. In exchange for selling a percentage (say 10%) of the units at effectively cost price the council will allow extra conditions e.g. extra floor height, less development contributions etc.
    There would have to be conditions though, perhaps the ‘affordible’ units have to be sold to a first home buyer, the units can’t be rented out, if the buyer/s sell within a certain time then any capital gains they make have to be given over to the council etc.

    This is something that could encourage developers to start buiilding as they will have an opportunity to potentially sell more units or lower their costs therefore making a larger profit which also allowing people to get into a new decent place and onto the property ladder in an area they probably want to live.

    1. Wasn’t Hobsonville meant to do something like that Matt where the State and Council gave some concessions for developers to build “affordable” housing (which seems to be an oxymoron given that you would want the bulk of your housing affordable 😛 ) in that Master Planned Community? Or did the authorities “dictate” that approach?

        1. Yeah I had heard that Hobsonville was becoming just another expensive development with little to no affordable housing as it is falling prey to the ability to extract higher commercial returns. I guess what I was suggesting was a more small scale solution, perhaps managed by the council. An example would be say the plans say you can only build to three stories in an area and a developer can get a solid enough return to do just that. The council could then say that if they add an additional floor with a proportion of it as affordable housing then they can add another floor to the development and get some development fee discounts.

          Developers are happy because they get to make more money from selling a few more units, council is happy because they get more intensification and first home buyers are happy because they get hopefully a nice place in a nice area for a much cheaper price than they would have other wise.

          I think the key from that Hobsonville experience is for the council to be much more heavily involved, something they could definitely do through their property and/or investment CCO’s

  4. During the boom times, there was a scheme in Ireland where first home buyers could buy at a significantly discounted price to get them into the market but with restrictions like the ones you meantion Matt L – must occupy (can’t rent out) can’t sell within 10yrs and if you do y0u have to pay back the “margin” (difference between market price and purchase price, on a sliding scale the longer you have held it within that first 10yrs).

    My understanding is it had a great take-up, but then their banks were a lot more generous with their cash than ours are now, when it comes to apartments anyway.

    Must be some good international models out there somewhere.

  5. The LAQC rules were going to be changed last year (year before?) but Key wimped out on it in a budget; the rationale was- get investment dollars out of keeping a housing bubble up and into NZ companies that actually manufacture and export.

    Fear from the Gummint, and a non stop tirade from the Property Investors Association watered that down a lot.

    It’s even mentioned the first article Patrick quotes-

    “We’re still on the look out,” Mr Bilkey said. “We look good on paper, and I’m a landlord myself so we thought it would be a bit different than a student looking for a flat.”

    Why don’t you live in the house you own then Mr Bilkey? You are part of the problem no?

  6. Minimum parking rules are a major barrier at present – a single dwelling is typically required to build two parks – which significantly drives up the cost. A relative recently bought a unit in the upper Symonds Street area, which had two carparks – a major council enforced cost on purchasers and developers.

  7. Isn’t one of the problems with “affordable housing” that when you make a developer sell, for example, 30% of their houses for cheap that they just get brought up by property developers who live in them for a year and then sell them on. Wouldn’t it be better to try and get systems like they have in England where you can get a a 50 year lease? I have heard of this kind of thing happening in lots of EU countries. I don’t know what it is about European property law that makes this possible but perhaps we could change our laws to enable it to happen here? Or have more council flats that you can rent for say 10 years on a fixed rent?

    1. Problem with your last 2 options is it doesn’t change the ownership issue. You would get to the end of 10/50yrs, then rent could skyrocket to the then market rate, forcing out the tenant who at the end of it all still doesn’t own their own dwelling.

    2. I don’t know what it is about European property law that makes this possible but perhaps we could change our laws to enable it to happen here?

      Nothing peculiar about their laws, just a societal tendency to allow it. There’s nothing in our property law that couldn’t allow a 50-year residential tenancy, but our landlords just won’t go for it.
      The other thing is that when you have such a long tenancy, you’re likely to want to make improvements in the way you would if you owned the property. Some European jurisdictions allow tenants more leeway to make property improvements, and then share some of any capital value increase should the landlord sell up before the tenancy is vacated. It’s things like that which encourage long-term tenancies, rather than anything in NZ law which forbids them. I could sign a 50-year tenancy with my landlord tomorrow, if we could negotiate suitable terms, but we’re not a country that views renting as a long-term living strategy; you’re looking to leave the country or buy your own place, not rent for decades.

    3. “Wouldn’t it be better to try and get systems like they have in England where you can get a a 50 year lease?”

      Are you talking about leasehold property? If so, I always regarded it as a throwback to feudal times where you essentially own the building for a period but rent the land from the descendents of the lord of the manor. It’s a system that has made the Duke of Westminster the richest man in the UK. The UK government was at one stage (Tony Blair?) trying to change the law to allow leaseholds to buy out their landlords.

      http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Leasehold

    4. That’s why I said there would have to be controls to prevent that, perhaps it is a function that the council would control

    5. I have worked for one of the largest affordable housing developers in the UK, and lived in a shared ownership house built by them. There are straightforward ways to setup affordable properties for sale, either through leasehold with legally binding rent price and rent review mechanisms, or through full sale mechanisms using covenants to dictate on-sell requirements in perpetuity.

      What does help is to have specialist affordable housing organisations (eg what are known as Housing Associations in the UK) present in the deal – leaving it all up to developers, or hoping for the government to play a role in individual land titles is a recipe for disaster. Our problem here is that these entities are fledgling and currently lack financial strength, legislative backing, and possibly adequate governance in some cases. In the UK many orginated from major charity benefactors going back 100 years or more. It will take time and major financial investment to get the ‘third sector’ up to the level of changing the housing market – but it will, and all strength to anyone in that role.

  8. Look at Rhubarb Lane. Looked like a great development but is being held up and hopefully goes ahead. As an investor it was difficult to buy there as the prices were far more than other apartments available. Then again maybe the capital gains may have been greater but the banks make it tought to borrow. I guessing this probably meant the majority of buyers were going to be owner/ occupied.

      1. I wonder if there is some way of using the RMA to stop wholesale development of new parking in Auckland? After all, more parking could lead to reduced PT use, council money having to be spent on roading or even increased vehicular emissions.

        1. Interesting that you suggest the RMA is there to stop things. You put your finger on one of the major reasons why we struggle to deliver good urban outcomes – our legislative framework was written with the intent of stopping things happening, rather than enabling things. Good things, like more housing.

        2. Is the problem with the RMA, or the way it’s interpreted by District Plans though? The RMA is a pretty flexible piece of legislation and was actually designed to encourage plans to be far less prescriptive than old District schemes had been under the 1977 Town and Country Planning Act.

          The problem is that most first generation District Plans were put in place by Councils that really hadn’t got their head around the RMA yet, and therefore ended up being really similar to the previous District schemes. This even includes really critical plans like the isthmus plan for Auckland City.

          I think there’s masses of scope under the RMA to have a District Plan that encourages really good housing. Just make all residential development a controlled activity, a couple of basic rules (max height and max site coverage perhaps) and leave the rest to urban design assessment criteria.

          There. Done.

      2. …and in a nutshell Rhubarb Lane represents many of the reasons why we’re not delivering new housing:

        – We’re let property prices become so high and allowed such restrictive lending practices that financing large development is nigh on impossible. Cash flow from a few car parks trumps any speculative (read debt-dependent) investment to create a better place, even when the potential development scale is very large. Tournament is of course a very smart business – cash-flow rich, and able to acquire large amounts of land which they will ultimately cash in on when petrol prices do finally undermine their core business.

        – Vast amounts of council regulations and site-specific development frameworks cannot prevent a lowest common denominator land use from occurring – despite previous Council control of the site! Does not bode well for future Joint Venture urban regeneration models unless Council get far more business-like in their control of land which they try to channel towards particular development outcomes.

        – Generally, NZ does not know how to do large-scale residential development, and their are precious few businesses with adequate capability in this field. Small-scale development is the norm – all the procedures are tuned to this (business and regulatory), aiming for large scale development tends to hit road blocks and significantly limit the potential number of developers / constructors – all the more so where anything other than standalone houses are concerned.

        So… to go back to the title of this post – we’re not building more dwellings because we can’t afford to, can’t force it to happen, and don’t know how to build at anything like a decent scale. It’s amazing how many capabilities we’ve lost since the 1950’s.

        1. One last thought. The only light at the end of the tunnel in this affair is that Tournament’s model of debt-free land purchase has to be a good thing. NZ has missed most of the global financial turmoil of the last 4 years (in fact, benefited indirectly so far) but other parts of the world are realising that it is good to have other options than just bankers and debt in control of economies.

          Cash-based development is the future, mark my words. It will take a long time, but it will return to something more akin to the Mutual Building Society models of the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries – local, accountable, and savings-based.

          The Herald is right to mark out this factor – even if we don’t like the fact that a parking company is in pole position for cash reserves.

        2. Yes Tournament is land banking- with a good cash flow, great business model. I’m envious. And they win either way: If we can get the vital intensification model past the forces of regression their site goes up in value and can be richly developed; if the morons of the car age prevail for longer or even -heaven forfend, build more lanes across the harbour, demand for parking keeps going up. Win winity win. And now you say they aren’t even geared, where do I sign?

          It does save this important site for a better project in the future, Rhubarb lane didn’t stack up because the land value was too high for such a low density use, so I’m not upset, anyway it included 3000 carparks! Probably the only viable part of the venture, or rather the dinky little laneways were really a lossleader for the car storage….

          That site call for a proper and fully urban solution, the low rise Rhubarb lane model needs a cheaper, and therefore probably further out site. Newmarket, Newton, etc.

        3. Yes you’re right. It was a bit too low density for the location. There were alot of great design aspects of the build though. Just hoping this area of town gets some kind of stimualation as it does seem isolated. One idea was to get the tram up to Vic park from Wynnard to Britomart. Would help activate this area.

          Maybe the quality of build of Rhubarb could be suited to Mt Albert?

  9. Another issue is, of course, companies who sink cash into housing. Small flats are ideal for this as they are cheaper than houses, can be used as a good alternative to hotels for visiting employees/guests and actually earn you money even without tenants (no taxes! yay!!). We got evicted from our last place because a company bought it out cheap (200k for a ~45m2) and they haven’t rented it out either, it’s been empty for months.

    Probably not a big factor but when the market is as tight as it is now every flat counts.

  10. Another another reason why we probably aren’t building as many houses as we could (it was something touched on by the productivity commission as well), it costs far too much to build houses. My parents are about to build a new house so have been busy going out show homes and meeting with building companies etc. to see what’s out there and get ideas. Today they went up to Hobsonville and they were told that it would cost them about $2300 per sqm yet this was for a town house of which a lot are being built so the costs should be much much less. By comparison the company they are going to use are charging $1700 per sqm for a bespoke house.

    1. Anything under or around 2k/sqm is going to be very basic, remember $300 of that is gst alone. Does that include siteworks and approvals?, even if so there is little chance that it can be all that ‘bespoke’. More like a few variations on a narrow range, beware of your parents exercising too much individuality as no doubt the fine print will require those to be fully charged.

      1. Not basic at all, in fact quite the opposite with high quality finishes. I know they have been driving a hard bargin though and even their lawyer was surprised at what they managed to get the building company to agree to. My point was more that at a place like Hobsonville we should be seeing a bit more economies of scale at play e.g. they can use one of a handful of already approved designs, they can buy materials in bulk to a larger degree etc.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *